by Philippa Noble
Development is the key method for economies to improve standards of
living and compete meaningfully on the world market. In this essay, due to the
governments’ heavy emphasis on improving infrastructure and industry in both
areas, judgements and comparisons will be focussed on the UN’s Sustainable
Development Goal 9: Industry, Innovation, and Infrastructure. These goals were
created to follow on from the UN Millenium Goals, continuing to strive for
greater global development of key areas: including industry, education, and
poverty. This includes the quality, reliability, and equitability of the
resulting development and these factors will be considered in the overall
judgement of each case study. Nevertheless, the key points that development
will be measured against in this essay are comprised of industrial output,
equity in placement, and sustainability.
Investopedia (2018) defines FDI as “an investment made by a firm or
individual in one country into business interests located in another country”.
This has played a major role in both Qingdao under Deng Xiaoping (seen here
through the lens of 1982-1989) and the Nkok SEZ (Special Economic Zone) since
2011 in bringing new business to the countries and diversifying production.
In the following essay, evaluations have been focussed on two main
sources: An article by economist, Jae Ho Chung in The China Quarterly, and the official Gabon SEZ website. The former
was written by an economist of South-East Asian descent, potentially leading to
biases in interpretations due to emotional links to the area. However, none of
the author’s interpretations have been included, only the raw data referenced in
his article so biases of that nature have been avoided. Although, as typically
sceptical Western economists, we may be wary of statistics forged by China
itself, we should recognise that socialism only works with a high level of
economic planning. If data is inaccurate or skewed in any way, the necessity of
planning within China would cause a collapse of administrative functions.
Therefore, despite acknowledging potential biases or corruption (in order to
promote Qingdao as a thriving area), a reasonable level of accuracy is very
likely as it had an important role within Chinese governing. The latter was
created and is maintained by employees of the Nkok SEZ, again making skewed
data for managerial gain likely. Furthermore, data inconsistencies between the
website and an official presentation could signal either corrupted data
reporting or outdated online content. For the purposes of this essay, where
data inconsistencies have been found, the lower bounds have been quoted so as
not to overstate the development in the Nkok SEZ. There is unfortunately no way
to show any skews in the data due to misreporting or corruption as there is no
other public source of data for the area. Nevertheless, as it is used to
promote investments, the data should be accurate so as to afford trust and
confidence in the management of the Nkok SEZ. It should also be noted that
exact comparisons of data were difficult to obtain as the produced data
reflected their different purposes. Jae Ho Chung’s quoted data set was
organised and extensive, making it easy to compare the growth between years,
however statistics found on the Gabonese SEZ website followed their need to be
promotional - making them circumstantial and likely only representing the
successes of the SEZ.
i) Qingdao, China 1982-1989
Figure 1. Map of China highlighting Qingdao. Reprinted from Google Maps, August 2018, retrieved from http://www.google.com/maps Copyright 2018 by Google. |
Between 1982 and 1989, China used preferential policies and favourable
tax rates within Qingdao to promote development and entrepreneurship (via FDI).
Due to a change in philosophy (from socialism to “socialism with Chinese
characteristics” - in essence, “whatever works”), it became general policy to
open up markets and ports to foreign business. However, at the beginning of the
1980s, after counsel from Ohira of Japan, the focus was to build institutions
and ensure vital resources were accessible. This is an important goal in a
planned economy, yet the move out of complete socialism was on the horizon. The
country-wide improvement and creation of institutions would go on to found more
business confidence - allowing firms to access credit, patents, and general
security. This would then boost innovation and entrepreneurship as new
companies had greater support and reward for their work.
Crucial policies behind opening up Qingdao’s markets include its
designation as a Coastal Open City in 1984. Three key effects of this (almost)
immeasurably aided Qingdao’s development. Firstly, the creation of development
zones allowed for hugely favourable tax rates in those areas. Enterprises were
afforded a two-year exemption from tax and a three-year reduction of tax (which
Jae Ho Chung shows amounted to 15% instead of the normal 33-55%). Lower tax
rates encouraged the relocation to and creation of firms within Qingdao as
profits increased for business owners, allowing potentially more research and
development (leading to recurring benefits for both the Chinese state through a
greater future tax revenue and for the business through new opportunities to gain
a greater market share). As seen in Fig.
2, a more favourable tax rate led to a shift right in Supply. Having
improved the profitability of producing within this market by reducing total
costs (and, thus, increasing the profit margin), the quantity produced
increased from Q1 to Q2. This shows the greater desirability of the market
(Qingdao) and its effects on increasing output within the area. Secondly, duties on imports of advanced
technology were completely removed. This made it easier (and more desirable)
for technology firms to relocate to Qingdao, supporting the previous
incentives. The policy also supported home-grown companies in bringing a new
sector into the economy. Furthermore, with incentives to import advanced
technologies, capital stocks swelled within Qingdao, bringing China to the
forefront of production and innovation with the capital to support it. Thirdly,
the area was deregulated and became, to an extent, autonomous. The Qingdao
local council gained approval authority over FDI projects of up to USD5 million
(which was later increased to USD30 million); the need for provincial licenses
to export was also removed. This deregulation made doing business with foreign
countries and companies much easier, as suddenly there was an easy way to
bypass the bureaucracy of the Chinese government at the time. Qingdao was now a
much more attractive area to do business in: it had been deregulated, taxes had
been slashed dramatically, and advanced technology imports were encouraged.
These policies cumulatively brought not only trade to Qingdao, but also
technology, capital, skills (as foreign companies would train their workers
from the local community), and jobs for its population. A drive by Deng
Xiaoping supported this by sending students to universities across the world.
Some feared a brain drain, where the top skilled workers and thinkers are lost
to other countries. However, a large proportion of the students sent overseas
returned, allowing China to profit from new, foreign knowledge, leading to
recurring benefits such as better quality innovation and education. As seen in Fig. 3, an increase in skill in the
workforce of an economy, increases efficiency and thus the amount of a good
able to be made in any given timeframe. Therefore, Supply shifts right,
extending Demand and reducing the price of the good to P2. Furthermore, a
secondary effect shows production increasing to Q2 - amounting to a greater
production level within the market. This explains the recurring impact of FDI
within the Qingdao area, which continued into the late 1990s. The immense
benefits of these policies were later furthered by Qingdao’s CEC designation in
1987, opening the city even more to foreign business.
Table 1: Gross Value of Industrial Output in Qingdao and the entire
People’s Republic of China in 100 million Yuan
|
Qingdao
|
PRC Total
|
% of PRC Total (self calculated)
|
1982
|
67.28
|
5,577.45
|
1.206
|
1983
|
77.63
|
6,166.54
|
1.259
|
1984
|
85.00
|
7,029.85
|
1.209
|
1985
|
99.37
|
8,294.51
|
1.198
|
1986
|
111.10
|
9,028.46
|
1.231
|
1987
|
129.00
|
10,364.67
|
1.245
|
1988
|
160.01
|
11,577.85
|
1.382
|
1989
|
176.84
|
12,294.56
|
1.438
|
Note: Data for GVIO in Qingdao
and the PRC total from Robert Ash and Y. Kueh (1996).
Table 2: Gross Value of Agricultural and Industrial Output in Qingdao
in Renminbi 100 million[1]
1978
|
68.3
|
1985
|
141.1
|
Note:
Reprinted from “A Sub-Provincial Recipe of Coastal Development in China: The
Case of Qingdao.”, by Jae Ho Chung, retrieved from The China Quarterly vol.
160, 1999.
This heavy focus on FDI and streamlined development of one city reaps
its reward when we look at the contemporary data. Table 1 shows the accelerated
growth in industrial output between 1982 and 1989, almost tripling within the
given time period. The benefits of Qingdao’s preferential policies are even
clearer when compared to the PRC total for each year. Qingdao as a city keeps
up with the PRC’s ambitious goals for rapid growth and even begins to expand
its share of the country’s output by 1988 and 1989. Although accounting for
less than 2% of the PRC’s total industrial output, it is important to remember
the comparative sizes of the entire country and the sea port. In fact, its
share of output grew by almost 20% between 1982 and 1989. These impressive
statistics are reinforced by Table 2, showing the growth of not only industrial
output but agricultural production as well. As a historically agriculture-based
area, the impacts of preferential policies within Qingdao would not be fully
observed if agricultural output was ignored. 1978 marks a period before open
policies were passed, making an apt comparison with Qingdao in 1985, during the
time these policies were enacted. Table 2 shows that overall output had more
than doubled within the data given.
A final point of crucial and telling data, the value of foreign
investments swelled almost immediately after the policies and statuses
mentioned above were implemented. In 1984, after being declared a Coastal Open
City, foreign investment totalled USD29.5 million (USD17.4 million contractual,
USD12.1 million actual, as detailed by Jae Ho Chung). Impressive on its own,
Qingdao really outdid itself when previous data is compared (where the past 5
years had totaled only USD8.9 million, calculated by Professor Chung). The
dramatic increase in foreign investment amounted to more than triple what was
received in the half decade beforehand. Similarly, having gained CEC status in
1987, Jae Ho Chung records that 14 foreign firms were established in Qingdao in
1988 - the delay being due to political opposition from Shandong causing issues
in obtaining permits for foreign trade.
There were many characteristics which were crucial to this example of
developmental accomplishment. Primarily, the frequent leadership changes within
Qingdao’s local authority allowed politicians to move past the traditional
ideology. This was key in promoting open policies and ensuring full commitment
to encouraging foreign investment. In comparison, earlier leaders were
“conservative and lukewarm about [open city reforms]” according to Jae Ho
Chung. A potential cause for its success was the political system in China. The
level of control upheld by the government meant that it could fully enforce its
policies and was generally not reliant on a favourable economic situation.
Furthermore, reforms could cover all parts of life. Qingdao was afforded
control of foreign investment contracts, but the government could change tax
rates, foreign policy, and growth goals in order to fit their own ambitions. In
this way, the reforms that Qingdao benefited from were supported in many ways
from many different sectors. It is important to note in comparing the two
cities in this essay that this introduction to the global market was welcomed
and encouraged by many other countries, and so China received support and
advisors from the World Bank and Japan (from the aforementioned Ohira). The
extent of the World Bank’s evaluation and recommendations to the Chinese
government certainly played a part in Qingdao’s development. Furthermore, the
welcoming stance taken by major trading partners contributed heavily to the
acceptability and encouragement of trading with a former Communist country.
This, therefore, promoted China as a trading partner, channeling business
through Coastal Open Cities such as Qingdao. Nevertheless, Qingdao’s success
was, like many things, tainted by inequality. These preferential policies
represented China’s focus on selected areas; by making some cities more
appealing, they focussed trade and development solely into these areas.
Therefore, Qingdao attracted more business for China as a whole, but also
became a hub for international trade for the surrounding area - meaning that
other cities suffered. In a country-wide sense, these reforms and this
development was not equitable. However, within Qingdao it could be assumed that
there was a reasonable level of equity, due to creation of jobs, training of
workers, and focus of advanced technology. This covers the broad sectors of
society - low skilled workers, skilled workers, and the well-off (as the
technology would likely have been marketed to them and by them).
Overall, the development of Qingdao must be deemed a great success. As
a stand alone city, its growth showed in its increased production and share of
the PRC’s output. Despite developing to the detriment of other cities, a
central hub of foreign trade could have also aided China as a whole in
providing a well-known, centralised place of business - cutting costs of
institutions, administration, and strengthening business confidence. The main
factor in this city’s history, I believe, was the openness of its leader, Deng
Xiaoping. In moving away from the dogmatic ideology of complete socialism, Deng
Xiaoping allowed the country and Qingdao to use its assets (such as major
ports) in new and profitable ways. And this, despite high levels of inflation
in the later years, is what I believe let Qingdao flourish, not only between
1982 and 1989, but well into the 1990s.
ii) Nkok SEZ, Gabon
2011-present
Figure 4. Map of Gabon highlighting Nkok. Reprinted from Google Maps, August 2018,
retrieved from http://www.google.com/maps Copyright 2018 by Google.
|
Ever since the agreement between the government of Gabon and the
international company Olam in 2010, the economy has been diversifying and
expanding - following the goals of the Gabonese government after the crash of
oil prices in recent years. In 2011, Nkok was created as a SEZ (Special
Economic Zone). This follows the Chinese model of development in specific areas,
creating a hub of foreign investment by using preferential policies. For
instance, Kate Dougla reports how foreign firms setting up in the Nkok SEZ
benefit from full tax exemption for the first ten years, then a lowered tax
rate of 10% for the next five years, following the theory in Fig. 2. This is notably more generous
than China’s example in Qingdao, however global markets are substantially less
enthused about the small Gabonese market than the booming economy of 1980s
China.
Kumar Mohan, head of GSEZ finance (as quoted in GSEZ.com, 2018) states
that "up to 80% on land acquisition and up to 60% on plant construction
can be financed by ECOBANK." Making transactions and investment as easy as
possible, the Gabonese government has done well in removing any answers to the
question “Why not?”. Strong institutions such as ECOBANK increase business
confidence and enable companies to gain capital or be set up. Fig. 5 shows that as institutions make
investors feel more comfortable supporting and creating firms within an
economy, AD shifts right (from AD1 to AD2) as more investments enter the
markets. This pushes real GDP from Y1 to Y2, showing an increase in production
and price, encouraging more firm activity through the promise of higher
profits. To further this, deregulation of the area means that a company can be
created in just 48 hours. For investors, Ruth Maclean reports (in
theguardian.com, 2016) how visas can be obtained in three days. This again
enables companies and investors, encouraging business through comparative ease
in tax, moving, and finance. Despite all the encouragement in these policies,
the area has worked hard to ensure that impressive infrastructure is in place
to support companies. For example, the Nkok SEZ has constructed a 230m long
quay to aid transport and shipping in supplies and encouraging exports.
The above policies have proved a great success. In the process of
creating the Nkok SEZ, Gabon has created “reliable” (as quoted in GSEZ.com,
2018 by Shailesh Barot) infrastructure supporting FDI. A functional water and
electricity supply, a police department, and residential areas are only a few
examples of the city-like infrastructure built into Nkok. It should be noted
that FDI is coming towards infrastructure, rather than infrastructure
developing due to FDI. Therefore, Gabon has made itself attractive instead of
being an initially desirable market. On another note, there has also been
external industry development (mainly through the Gabon-Olam partnership).
Olam’s position in Gabon has grown within the palm industry and by promoting
entrepreneurism. Program GRAINE has led to the development of 200,000 hectares
of plantations which are owned by smallholders (structured into cooperatives).
A primary goal of the Gabonese government was to diversify the economy, having
suffered following volatile oil prices. Thus, the multi-sectoral zone that is
Nkok SEZ has certainly met their aim, housing companies from different
industries including furniture, cement making, and electronics. Finally, a goal
of any developing, or indeed developed, country is to create jobs. The Nkok SEZ
website (GSEZ.com, n.d) boasts the creation of 1800 direct jobs in 2016, 60% of
which were local workers. It shows that the Nkok SEZ is supporting not only the
Gabonese economy, but the local community as well.
Overall, Gabon’s development of the Nkok SEZ has been widely
successful. Likely due to slightly desperate preferential policies, around 80
companies have been involved in the Nkok SEZ, showing great progress for the
area. Plots within the zone are still empty or being constructed, meaning that
there is potential for even higher returns, however also insinuating that
interest in investments is not incredibly high. Referring to Goal 9,
infrastructure has been developed by the Gabonese government and by links with
foreign investment, leading to greater security in institutions, residencies,
and jobs in the area. Furthermore, innovation has also been addressed through
Olam’s promotion of cooperatives in Program GRAINE. Industry has grown and
diversified, achieving one of the core goals of the Nkok development area. From
the partnership with Olam International to the latest investor within Nkok SEZ,
the development in the zone has been not only due to the work of the government
but also FDI. This has played a major role in improving, driving, and adding to
the community in Nkok. Gabon has even bypassed the worries of many: growing
Chinese political control over Africa. China has only been represented in a
small way within Nkok’s development, an area that was built and improved by
Gabon itself and therefore avoiding all the finance issues linked with China’s
so-called “Debt Trap Diplomacy”.
The two case studies explored above are remarkably similar. Their
existence as port cities lends both Qingdao and the Nkok SEZ to FDI-led
development. Shipping and international links are much easier to uphold when
the quayside can be seen through the window. Thus Gabon’s tendency to make
trade incredibly easy shines through from even the most fundamental of
characteristics - its geography. Aside from the concrete, Qingdao begins to
differ from Nkok. Preferential policies used in each city are very close in
essence, yet the extent to which the Nkok SEZ almost begs for trade is not
matched by Qingdao. With prior links to South Korea and Japan, perhaps Qingdao
did not need to drop tax rates as far or cater to companies as much as Nkok. Furthermore,
the small 2.07 million person market of Gabon really cannot compare to China’s
historic population of over 1000 million. This naturally makes the investments
into Qingdao more attractive as there is room for a business and market to grow
within a much larger population. As Wu Jingchun, an economic advisor, said
about Gabon (chinadaily.com, 2014): “If you sell everyone in the country two
cellphones that is only 3 million phones”. Perhaps lower tax rates and more
extensive preferential policies makes up for Nkok’s lack of a large market.
Nevertheless, the use of such policies is a defining characteristic in both
cases. On a similar note, the focus on one area and the creations of SEZ or
CEC-esque zones are typical of Qingdao and Nkok. Therefore, the role of the
government is also very similar. With Deng Xiaoping looking to move away from
all-encompassing socialism, the ideologies and participation of (local)
government are almost identical. Due to the smaller population, Gabon’s
government can act directly in the Nkok SEZ but plays a similar role to the
local government in Qingdao. Deregulation, preferential policies, and central
rule are common features that allow some areas to benefit from development
while others are neglected.
The main difference between these two examples is the substantial GDP
growth that China benefited from within the period 1982-1989. Here, China
averaged 10.575% growth each year, whereas, between 2013 and 2016, Gabon only
averaged 3.975% growth per year. Of course, there are other factors dictating
growth, however as the instances studied above are typical of the development
in each country (Qingdao was only one of many designated Coastal Open Cities)
it seems a fair comparison of the respective effects of each development. Both
are taken in comparable stages of their development - i.e. in the early stages
of FDI where the effects have not fully been realised. So perhaps, despite the
modest growth enjoyed by Gabon since Nkok has been open for business, in the
future there will be higher rates comparable with Qingdao’s rocketing growth in
the 1990s. The evidence shows that China has benefited from much higher growth
than Gabon can ever aim for - yet this appears to be reliant on China’s goliath
population and its ideological revelation under Deng Xiaoping. Unfortunately,
Gabon has neither a large population, nor been a menacing political rival to
the First or Second World resulting in a warm welcome when they return to
capitalism or socialism respectively. These assets cannot be easily
manufactured, so it seems that Gabon’s growth will follow the pattern of
China’s yet at a much lower level.
To comment on the effectiveness of these policies, it appears that in
coastal cities with FDI-led development, making trade as easy as possible is a
guarantee for success. The evidence from Qingdao suggests that initial growth
is much lower than after a 2 to 5 year lag. Nevertheless, support from the
global scene must be achieved to attract business - through links with the
World Bank, IMF, or other international trade links. China benefited from World
Bank counsel and the West’s welcome after rejecting complete socialism; Gabon
also received loans from the IMF and generally has trade backing from China and
other countries looking to cash-in on emerging markets. This certainly paints a
rosy picture of the future for Gabon; following all logic, growth should boom
within the next few years. Yet perhaps, more Special Economic Zones should be
created to properly follow the model of China - not to focus all development in
one city, but still focus it enough to create multiple hubs of foreign
investment within the country.
References
(n.d.). Retrieved from
https://www.google.com/maps/place/Qingdao, Shandong,
China/@31.7855396,110.2362425,5.04z/data=!4m5!3m4!1s0x35960fd582f8f06b:0x614d82fa614cf2f3!8m2!3d36.067108!4d120.382609
(n.d.). Retrieved from
https://www.google.com/maps/place/GSEZ GABON SPECIAL ECONOMIC ZONE
SA/@-0.7349906,10.239211,8z/data=!4m5!3m4!1s0x107f3b75eb3b31cf:0x62026a7e8ce2ecb!8m2!3d0.4079131!4d9.4381574
About
the Sustainable Development Goals – United Nations Sustainable Development. (2018). Retrieved from
https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/sustainable-development-goals/
Bucknall, K. (1997, 07). The Chinese
Economy Under Deng Xiaoping.Robert F. Ash , Y. Y. Kueh. The China Journal, 38,
188-188. doi:10.2307/2950348
Chinese companies face challenges in
Gabon. (n.d.). Retrieved from
http://africa.chinadaily.com.cn/business/2014-04/14/content_17431432.htm
Chung, J. H. (1999, 12). A Sub-Provincial
Recipe of Coastal Development in China: The Case of Qingdao. The China Quarterly, 160, 919. doi:10.1017/s0305741000001387
GSEZ - Gabon Special Economic Zone |
gsez.com. (n.d.). Retrieved from http://www.gsez.com/
Gabon luring foreign companies through
attractive incentives. (2014, February 21). Retrieved from https://www.howwemadeitinafrica.com/gabon-luring-foreign-companies-through-attractive-incentives/28506/
Maclean, R. (2016, August 16). Gabon aims
to cut yawning poverty gap by ending its dependency on oil | Ruth Maclean.
Retrieved from
https://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2016/aug/16/gabon-yawning-poverty-gap-end-dependency-oil
Staff, I. (2018, April 22). Foreign Direct
Investment - FDI. Retrieved from https://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/fdi.asp
Comments
Post a Comment
Comments with names are more likely to be published.